Solve Cournot oligopoly model via collocation

Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD

This demo is based on the original Matlab demo accompanying the Computational Economics and Finance 2001 textbook by Mario Miranda and Paul Fackler.

Original (Matlab) CompEcon file: demapp07.m

Running this file requires the Python version of CompEcon. This can be installed with pip by running

!pip install compecon --upgrade

Last updated: 2022-Oct-22


About

To illustrate implementation of the collocation method for implicit function problems, consider the example of Cournot oligopoly. In the standard microeconomic model of the firm, the firm maximizes profit by equating marginal revenue to marginal cost (MC). An oligopolistic firm, recognizing that its actions affect price, takes the marginal revenue to be \(p + q\frac{dp}{dq}\), where \(p\) is price, \(q\) is quantity produced, and \(\frac{dp}{dq}\) is the marginal impact of output on market price. The Cournot assumption is that the firm acts as if any change in its output will be unmatched by its competitors. This implies that

\[\begin{equation*} \frac{dp}{dq} = \frac{1}{D'(p)} \end{equation*}\]

where \(D(p)\) is the market demand curve.

Suppose we wish to derive the effective supply function for the firm, which specifies the quantity \(q = S(p)\) it will supply at any price. The firm’s effective supply function is characterized by the functional equation

\[\begin{equation*} p + \frac{S(p)}{D'(p)} - MC(S(p)) = 0 \end{equation*}\]

for all positive prices \(p\). In simple cases, this function can be found explicitly. However, in more complicated cases, no explicit solution exists.

Initial tasks

import numpy as np
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
from compecon import BasisChebyshev, NLP

The model

Parameters

Here, the demand elasticity and the marginal cost function parameter are

alpha, eta = 1.0, 3.5
D = lambda p: p**(-eta)

Approximation structure

A degree-25 Chebychev basis on the interval [0.5, 3.0] is selected; also, the associated collocation nodes p are computed.

n, a, b =  25, 0.5, 2.0
S = BasisChebyshev(n, a, b, labels=['price'], y=np.ones(n))
p = S.nodes
S2 = BasisChebyshev(n, a, b, labels=['price'], l=['supply'])
S2.y = np.ones_like(p)

Residual function

Suppose, for example, that

(5)\[\begin{equation} D(p) = p^{-\eta} \quad\text{and}\quad MC(q) = \alpha\sqrt{q} + q^2 \end{equation}\]

Then the functional equation to be solved for S(p),

(6)\[\begin{equation} \left[p - \frac{S(p)p^{\eta+1}}{\eta}\right] -\left[\alpha\sqrt{S(p)} + S(p)^2\right] = 0 \end{equation}\]

has no known closed-form solution.

def resid(c):
    S.c = c  # update interpolation coefficients
    q = S(p) # compute quantity supplied at price nodes
    marginal_income = p - q * (p ** (eta+1) / eta)
    marginal_cost = alpha * np.sqrt(q) + q ** 2
    return  marginal_income - marginal_cost 

Notice that resid only takes one argument. The other parameters (Q, p, eta, alpha) should be declared as such in the main script, were Python’s scoping rules will find them.

Solve for effective supply function

Class NLP defines nonlinear problems. It can be used to solve resid by Broyden’s method.

cournot = NLP(resid)
S.c = cournot.broyden(S.c, tol=1e-12)

Plot demand and effective supply for m=5 firms

prices = np.linspace(a, b, 501)

fig1, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.plot(5 * S(prices), prices, label='Supply')
ax.plot(D(prices), prices, label='Demand')

ax.set(title='Cournot Effective Firm Supply Function', 
       xlabel='Quantity',
       ylabel='Price',
       xlim=[0, 4],
       ylim=[0.5, 2])

ax.legend();
../../_images/07 Solve Cournot oligopoly model via collocation_16_0.png

Plot residual

Notice that resid does not take explicit parameters, so to evaluate it when prices are prices we need to assign p = prices.

In order to assess the quality of the approximation, one plots the residual function over the approximation domain. Here, the residual function is plotted by computing the residual at a refined grid of 501 equally spaced points.

p = prices
fig2, ax = plt.subplots()

ax.hlines(0, a, b, 'k', '--', lw=2)
ax.plot(prices, resid(S.c))
ax.set(title='Residual Function for Cournot Problem',
       xlabel='Quantity',
       ylabel='Residual');
../../_images/07 Solve Cournot oligopoly model via collocation_19_0.png

Plot demand and effective supply for m=1, 3, 5, 10, 15, 20 firms

fig3, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=[9,4])

ax.set(title='Industry Supply and Demand Functions', 
       xlabel='Quantity',
       ylabel='Price',
       xlim=[0, 12])

lcolor = [z['color']  for z in plt.rcParams['axes.prop_cycle']]

for i, m in enumerate([1, 3, 5, 10, 15, 20]):
    ax.plot(m*S(prices), prices) # supply
    ax.annotate(f'm={m:d}', [m*S(1.2)+.025, 1.4-i/12], color=lcolor[i], fontsize=12)
        
ax.plot(D(prices), prices, linewidth=4, color='grey') # demand
ax.annotate('demand', [10, 0.6], color='grey', fontsize=12);
../../_images/07 Solve Cournot oligopoly model via collocation_21_0.png

Plot equilibrium price as a function of number of firms m

m = np.arange(1,26)
x0 = np.full_like(m, 0.7, dtype=float) #initial guess
eqprices = NLP(lambda p: m*S(p) - D(p)).broyden(x0)

fig4, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.set(title='Cournot Equilibrium Price as Function of Industry Size', 
       xlabel='Number of Firms',
       ylabel='Price')
ax.plot(m, eqprices);
../../_images/07 Solve Cournot oligopoly model via collocation_23_0.png